Piero Cipollone: Interview with Reuters
Interview with Piero Cipollone, conducted by Balazs Koranyi and
Francesco Canepa6 February 2025
The ECB has said that the
direction of travel for monetary policy is clear, but the timing and
extent of moves is not. What does this guidance mean to you?
We are moving towards the target. The direction of inflation
is clear, despite some small bumps. All incoming information points to
a convergence with the target in 2025 and this is what our models are
also telling us.
Our models include market expectations for
the interest rate path, so this convergence with the inflation target
is coherent with a declining interest rate path.
Everything is
of course contingent on the information at the time of the forecasts,
and we will have a new forecast round in March. Before then, we’ll get
another inflation print, we’ll have more details on the composition of
inflation, and all these feed into the model, as do market
expectations for interest rates.
Does that mean implicitly
that you are comfortable with market expectations for further rate
cuts as they are embedded in the projections?
That was
conditional on the information we had in December. I am comfortable as
long as that path takes us to the target in the medium term in a
sustainable way.
What does the data since that December
meeting tell you?
Overall, I think the direction is the same.
I don’t see huge changes in our view, except trade tensions. The
overall understanding of where we are going is there, the fundamentals
haven’t changed, so I do not expect a big change in direction.
One thing that might happen is a trade war with the United
States. How would that affect your thinking?
It depends on
details such as whether we retaliate, precisely what these tariffs are
going to be levied on, and how China is affected.
If tariffs
are imposed on us, the most immediate impact will be on growth.
The price of goods will be higher in the United States. Who is
going to absorb the cost? It could be that European companies, in
order to defend their market share, might be willing to sacrifice a
bit of their margin in order to stay in the market. We have seen this
many times and European firms have a great ability to adjust. Part of
this sacrifice might be recovered through the exchange rate. So, in
the end, the overall impact may not be that big.
What concerns
me more is if President Trump engages in a full trade war with China.
This is a more serious threat because China has 35% of the world’s
manufacturing capacity. Trade barriers will force China to sell its
goods elsewhere and the competition from China could be a serious
threat to us. These goods showing up in Europe could have both a
deflationary and a contractionary impact because they would crowd out
local products.
The uncertainty is exceptionally high,
everything is in motion. And we can’t assess where it’s all going
until things fall in place.
It’s true we have a goods surplus
with the United States. But if you add in services and look at the
overall current account, then the balance is close to zero.
Looking at the very short term, can you support a rate cut in
March, as some of your colleagues are already saying?
I don’t
want to seem elusive, but the uncertainty is so high that anything can
happen. We all agree there is still room for adjusting rates
downwards. But we need to be extremely careful. It’s important to
stress this idea of a meeting-by-meeting, data-dependent approach. I
want to enter the meeting with an open mind, see the staff assessment
and process incoming data.
But we also all agree that we are
still in a restrictive territory.
Suppose tariffs on China
stay, that’s a huge demand shock. On the other hand, we have energy
prices moving upwards. It could be a transitory phenomenon, but what
if this is more entrenched?
How far are we from the neutral
rate and why has the neutral gone up?
When you have an
estimate range that is 50 or 75 basis points, then it’s a conceptual
tool and doesn’t have much bearing on policy, given the high
uncertainty. Take estimates that it is between 1. 75% and 2. 25%.
Those are two completely different monetary policies, if you are close
to target. It’s such a wide range that one number could imply that you
are undershooting and another that you are overshooting. So “neutral”
is a very powerful analytical concept but not terribly useful for
setting monetary policy, given this embedded uncertainty.
It’s
possible this rate went up but it’s also possible it stayed unchanged
given how wide the band is.
You say you are clearly
restrictive now. Would that still apply after the next cut? When does
the debate start on when restrictive ends?
We are almost on
target. The closer you get to target, the less you’ll need to stay
restrictive.
It’s also true we have been overly optimistic on
growth and had to cut our growth forecasts three times since June. So,
it is possible that the recovery is not as strong as expected and thus
the inflationary pressure coming from demand is weaker. This could
prompt us to reassess our concept of restrictiveness.
Could
this mean that you need to become accommodative to avoid an
undershoot?
I assess the risk around inflation to be balanced
and I don’t have evidence of a possible undershoot. Long-term
inflation expectations are also very well anchored.
The latest
information, especially the rise in the cost of energy, makes me think
that we should be prudent. It might be a transitory phenomenon, but
prices have risen substantially. Consumer expectations have also gone
up a little as they are very reactive to short-term developments.
I’m not saying that risks are moving towards being on the
upside, but we have no evidence of undershooting either.
Do
the growth revisions suggest fundamental changes in how the economy
functions?
Growth has been disappointing, especially because
of investments. Consumption may have been less buoyant than we
thought, but it remains broadly on the path that we are expecting. The
fundamentals for rising consumption are there. Real incomes are
increasing, employment is high, inflation is declining and consumer
confidence is holding steady.
The real problem is investments,
and that is only partially linked to monetary policy. The culprit is
uncertainty. Investments have been weak since the summer given the
overall uncertainty and the direction of trade policy after the US
election.
My sense is that people are holding out before
making important investment decisions. There is of course a cost
component related to interest rates. But you see that people are
investing just to replace old capital stock.
What can the ECB
do about it?
We have to take care of the cost component and
avoid being unduly restrictive. Our goal should be to have the economy
growing close to potential and to contribute to reducing uncertainty
as much as possible.
Could another targeted longer-term
refinancing operation help investments?
It doesn’t seem to me
that the lack of available funding is the issue. We have seen some
tightening of credit conditions but that’s not the key factor here.
Last week we were talking about a 25% tariff, today not
anymore, and tomorrow we don’t know. All companies are trying to
understand where it’s all going so that they can make investment
decisions.
How does this uncertainty affect the labour market?
There could be some softening of the labour market but overall
we have been positively surprised. We went through a huge disinflation
process with a very strong labour market.
Labour hoarding has
two dimensions. One is the cost. Overall, the cost is still relatively
low because, by some measures, real wages are still below the pre-
pandemic level. The second reason is that firms are afraid of losing
skilled labour and this is still the case.
The labour market
is softening, however. The problem is manufacturing essentially. But
even there we see some light at the end of the tunnel. There seem to
be some initial signs of recovery in the Purchasing Managers’ Index
and the Economic Sentiment Indicator. I was surprised to see that
confidence in the construction sector and manufacturing activity have
bottomed out, and we see some possible signs of recovery. Services are
holding up overall. If there is some softening in terms of demand for
labour, possibly there will be a pick-up in productivity which will
reduce the unit labour cost overall. We obviously need to monitor it
because, with all this uncertainty, we could see a deterioration. But
I am not overly concerned about the labour market.
Adding up
what you said about these modest signs of recovery in manufacturing,
does that mean you still believe in the soft-landing narrative and you
don’t see a recession?
We might not be booming but I am not
expecting a recession at all. I think consumption will slowly go up
because the fundamentals are there, labour income is growing, the cost
of borrowing is declining, inflation is declining, and consumer
confidence is basically holding up, so it’s possible that the savings
rate will decline from a historic high. So, overall, I think
consumption will keep going – and that is a big chunk of the economy.
Investment should recover too, as soon as all this uncertainty
dissipates. First, one cannot hold back forever: imagine you have a
bunch of cumulated investment decisions to make. Even if a small
percentage of them go through, it will be a positive and you will see
that in investment. Second, less restrictive financial conditions are
slowly being transmitted to the cost of financing. And third, in
2025-26 we should see an acceleration in the spending of Next
Generation EU funds in Europe.
Moving to the digital euro.
Could you give us an update?
We have started the procurement
process and we will be selecting suppliers in June, but the contracts
are such that they will only be triggered if the Governing Council
decides to issue the digital euro. We have been working on the
rulebook and we will be able to finalise it shortly after we have firm
EU legislation in place. For example, whether people can have access
to one or more wallets will have an influence on the rulebook, so if
we don’t have a final legislation, we cannot finalise the rulebook.
But it will not take long once the legislation is approved because we
have done as much work as possible in the absence of a firm
legislation. So the procurement is done and the rulebook is almost
done. We are also working with the market to leverage the innovation
potential of the digital euro. We think there is huge potential in
conditional payments to increase the quality and the menu of the
offering on payments.
So that is a payment that only happens
if a certain condition is fulfilled, right?
Today there is only
one type of conditional payment and it is based on time: pay this
amount to this person on this date. We think we can do better than
that. To make sure that this intuition is right, at the end of
October, we issued a call for innovation partnerships. We were
surprised to receive 100 offers. People want to experiment with new
ideas. We will be doing that for the next six months and we will then
prepare a report.
Would conditional payments require a
blockchain? How else would the condition be verified?
No, it’s
not a matter of blockchain. If you have a way to register the
transaction on the ledger through a sort of token, that is a
possibility. But technicians tell me you can make a transaction
conditional even on a traditional ledger. We are working on that, but
the information that I can give you is that we can do better than what
we are doing today on conditional payment, regardless of the
underlying technology. The technology has a bearing on many
dimensions, for example latency and privacy.
Could you give me
an example of a conditional payment that could be settled in digital
euro?
For example, if the train is late, today you have to ask
to be reimbursed. You could have a solution in which you only pay if
the condition is automatically verified.
To conclude with
where we are in the preparation phase, let me add that since the
digital euro is a product, we have to market it. So, we are engaging
with focus groups and using surveys to understand how to best finalise
the product in order to meet people’s expectations. We are on
schedule, so we should be ready to take a decision on moving to the
next project phase by November 2025. I don’t know whether at that time
the Governing Council will already be able to take a decision to
eventually issue a digital euro because that depends on whether we
have a legislation at that point. We have been clear that we would not
take any decision about the issuance of a digital euro before the
legislative act has been adopted.
We had expected legislation
on the digital euro some time ago. What’s holding up the process? Are
you sensing a lack of political will?
I wouldn’t say there’s a
lack of political will. I think people want to understand the whole
process. The European Commission issued legislation in June 2023, then
the European Parliament started to work on that, but mentally they
were not there because there was an EU election coming up. Everything
stopped. They are starting to work on this now so, to be fair to them,
they didn’t have much time. By contrast, in the Council of the
European Union’s working party, work is progressing. As far as I know,
they have gone through all of the legislative proposal and they are
now focusing on the issues that still need to be worked out. When both
the Council and the Parliament have agreed internally, they will sit
down with the Commission and try to finalise the legislation. So, we
hope they will be able to reach an agreement internally before the
summer. But again, political processes are complex and there are many
things on the table. Obviously the sooner the better, but we fully
understand their needs. My sense is that there is an increased sense
of urgency because of the position that has been taken by the new US
Administration. The fact that the US President went in so strong on
this idea of promoting worldwide US dollar-denominated stablecoins
obviously is a signal. The political world is becoming more alert to
this. And it’s possible that we will see an acceleration in the
process.
Stablecoins are similar to money market funds that
people use if they don’t want to go via the banking system, whereas
the digital euro, with its holding limit, will purely be a means of
payment. Why do you think a digital euro would be a good response to
stablecoins?
You’re right, for as long as stablecoins are not
used as a means of payment. My sense is that they will be. This is
worrisome because if people in Europe start to use stablecoins to pay,
given that most of them are American and dollar-based, they will be
transferring their deposits from Europe to the United States. It may
start with peer-to-peer, cross-border transactions. Then an American
tourist may be able to use stablecoins instead of using a credit card,
for example. So stablecoins can enter the payment space, for example,
if they can compete with card schemes by reducing the price for the
merchant. We have seen that important payment providers have already
issued stablecoins, like PayPal, for example.
Turning now to
bitcoin, we know that the ECB has got repo lines and swap lines with
other central banks. Would the ECB maintain those with a central bank
that has bitcoins among its reserves?
It’s an interesting
question. Fortunately we don’t have to think about that right now
because no major central bank is thinking about that.
One is
hypothesising.
We would need to do a risk management
assessment of that. Let’s see if any central bank enters this space
because I don’t fully see the rationale for it. We will assess it at
that point in time, if it happens. I am trying to be rational and
think about why I should invest in bitcoin or another crypto-asset.
The only rationale is if one thinks that the price will always go up.
It doesn’t have any underlying value, there is no asset backing it,
there is no earning model.
On that, it’s a bit like gold.
The structures of the two markets are completely different:
the transparency of the market, the concentration. So, I would be
careful about making the analogy. I don’t know how deep the market for
gold is, but there are central banks in that market, and not just
because of a legacy system. We should not stop at a superficial
analogy between gold and bitcoin.
Why do central banks invest
in gold, other than legacy?
It’s in part due to legacy, but
gold has intrinsic, commercial and industrial value. Bitcoin does not
have any of that.
We’ve seen gold and bitcoin make all-time
highs at the same time. Or should we say that fiat currencies are
making all-time lows?
Fiat currencies allow you, among other
things, to pay. Good luck trying to pay in bitcoin or gold. Central
bank money is the safest asset you can imagine and it's relatively
stable in terms of what you can buy with it.