Frank Elderson: Monetary policy in the climate and nature crises: preserving a “Stabilitätskultur”
Speech by Frank Elderson, Member of the Executive Board of the ECB and
Vice-Chair of the Supervisory Board of the ECB, at the Bertelsmann
Stiftung, BerlinFrankfurt am Main, 22 November 2023
The concept
of Stabilitätskultur, or culture of stability, was first used by
former Bundesbank President Helmut Schlesinger in 1991. In coining
this phrase, he wanted to emphasise that stable money – the remit of
central banks − not only required a stability-oriented policy from the
central bank, but also from the government and society at large.
In the face of the current climate and nature crises,
Schlesinger’s insight that stability-oriented institutions cannot
pursue their objectives in isolation could hardly be more relevant.
The Emissions Gap Report published by the UN earlier this week
concludes that the world is on a global heating path of 3°C, far above
the Paris Agreement objective of well below 2°C. [1] And earlier
studies have shown that 25% of species are vulnerable and an estimated
one million species face a risk of extinction. [2] Today I will convey
that a culture of stability can only be preserved if climate and
nature are stable. Most central banks and banking supervisors around
the world have acknowledged this in recent years. And the ECB is
putting it into practice in all its tasks and responsibilities,
including our banking supervision and our monetary policy, the latter
being the focus of my remarks today. Taking climate and nature into
account
As I have often said before and will reiterate today to
remove any possibly remaining doubt: central banks and supervisors
like the ECB are not, and do not intend to be, climate and nature
policymakers. [3] Moreover, as an independent central bank, the ECB is
not directly bound by the European Climate Law that since 2021 has
committed the EU to achieving climate neutrality by 2050 with interim
deadlines. This does not mean, however, that the ECB is allowed to
ignore the Climate Law. The EU Treaty requires environmental
protection to be integrated into the definition and implementation of
EU policies. The Treaty imposes an obligation on us to take into
account the objectives of climate and nature-related legislation when
performing our monetary policy and banking supervision tasks.
[4]
This is not just a legal reality. The massive impact of the
climate and nature crises on the economy, including the financial
system, makes it crystal clear that we must take climate and nature
into account. In fact, if we didn’t do so, we would risk failing to
deliver on our mandate. The relevance of climate and nature for
monetary policy[5]
At least five economic consequences of the
climate and nature crises are specifically relevant to monetary policy
and our primary objective of maintaining price stability.
First, we can expect macroeconomic volatility – including the
volatility of inflation – to increase further as climate and nature
events occur more frequently and have a greater impact on the economy.
Second, climate and nature shocks complicate monetary policy
analysis and make it harder to assess the appropriate monetary policy
response. Whether we are dealing with more frequent extreme weather
events and nature degradation or actions to support the green
transition, climate and nature events may largely materialise in the
form of supply shocks, implying that economic activity and inflation
move in opposite directions. Generally speaking, as supply shocks
involve a potential trade-off, they are more challenging for central
banks than demand shocks. If supply shocks persistently affect
inflation, they may generate risks for price stability and so trigger
a change to monetary policy that would further dampen economic
activity. If, however, supply shocks are temporary and pose no risk to
medium-term price stability, central banks can look through them and
avoid slowing down the economy.
Third, the ongoing climate and
nature crises may cause the equilibrium rate of interest to fall. The
equilibrium rate is the interest rate that prevails when all shocks to
the economy have dissipated and monetary policy is neither
accommodative nor restrictive. Greater uncertainty owing to the
climate and nature crises and the necessity to build up resilience to
shocks can increase economic agents’ propensity to save, thereby
lowering the equilibrium interest rate. A lower equilibrium rate
implies that future monetary policy could come up against the
effective lower bound for interest rates more often, though the more
frequent occurrence of negative supply shocks that I referred to
earlier may mitigate this effect to some extent.
Fourth,
financial risks arising from climate and nature crises can impair the
soundness of financial institutions. Should these risks materialise –
despite all our efforts as a banking supervisor to mitigate them[6] –
the transmission of our monetary policy could be affected. Monetary
policy decisions would be transmitted through the financial system and
the economy in a less orderly and less predictable manner, potentially
hampering our effectiveness in achieving our price stability
objective.
Fifth, the risks that may affect financial
institutions can also undermine the solidity of the central bank
balance sheet. Unlike commercial banks, central banks are not profit-
seeking and only expose themselves to financial risks if helpful in
achieving price stability. This is especially true when such risks can
cause financial losses that could erode confidence in the central
bank’s ability to deliver price stability. Prudent central banks will
thus seek to avoid any climate and nature-related financial risks that
do not contribute to price stability.
I am not aware of any
evidence suggesting that seeking exposures to climate and nature-
related financial risks might help in securing and maintaining price
stability. On the contrary, available evidence suggests the opposite
is true. In fact, when we align our portfolios with the market status
quo of high exposure to climate and nature-related financial risks, we
risk adding to macroeconomic volatility. As already mentioned, this
would make it harder to achieve the monetary policy goal of price
stability.
To summarise, in the pursuit of price stability,
central banks benefit from mitigation of climate and nature-related
risks, which – as analysis consistently shows − is best ensured by
securing a timely and orderly transition. [7] The ECB’s climate
actions so far
Against this backdrop, in 2021 the ECB
explicitly acknowledged that climate change had profound implications
for price stability through its impact on the structure and cyclical
dynamics of the economy and the financial system. In the case of the
ECB, actions on climate equally serve our secondary objective, as also
laid down in the EU Treaties, of supporting the general economic
policies in the EU, which include the EU’s climate objectives.
Accordingly, we unveiled an ambitious climate action plan covering
macroeconomic modelling, financial stability monitoring, data
collection, risk assessment capabilities and our monetary policy
operations.
And this wasn’t just a plan. We delivered on it,
just like we said we would. Let me give you some specific examples of
how we have put into practice what were still mere ambitions back in
2021.
First, we have made significant progress in improving
our capabilities to take climate considerations into account in the
macroeconomic analyses that inform our monetary policy assessment. For
example, we can now use a suite of macroeconomic models to analyse the
economic consequences of the green transition in the euro area. Using
this suite of models, staff have found that an increase in carbon
pricing in line with the International Energy Agency’s net-zero
scenarios may have a limited impact on economic growth and inflation.
[8] The analysis also suggests that due to the low substitutability of
non-sustainable and sustainable consumption, the carbon price path
envisaged by the Agency may not actually be sufficient to achieve net-
zero objectives. This implies that either carbon prices would need to
increase further, or that additional regulation would be required, or
a combination of both. Again, we would need to be ready to take into
account any monetary policy implications that could arise as a result.
Acknowledging that climate factors can have an impact on our
monetary policy assessment is not just “what-if” thinking. ECB
research shows that the related effects are already materialising. For
example, ECB staff estimates suggest that the heatwave in 2022 pushed
up food price inflation by up to 0. 67 percentage points, with the
impact lasting well into 2023. [9] Thanks to our enhanced analytical
capabilities, earlier this year we were able to acknowledge for the
first time – in our monetary policy statement issued after the
Governing Council meeting – that climate factors posed an upside risk
to the inflation outlook. [10]
Second, between October 2022 and
July 2023 we started tilting our reinvestments of corporate bonds
towards issuers that have a better climate performance. In so doing,
we can avoid undue exposures to climate-related risks that are
detrimental to price stability and align the way we administer our
monetary policy more closely with the EU’s general economic policies.
As of July 2023 we suspended bond purchases in our asset purchase
programme, including corporate bonds, to support the downward pressure
exerted by our current policy rates in order to bring inflation back
to our 2% target. If required from a monetary policy perspective, the
established direction of the tilt will set the minimum benchmark for
any future corporate bond purchases. [11]
In addition to our
bond holdings, we are also looking at the collateral framework that we
apply in relation to banks’ participation in our lending operations.
We have decided that only assets that comply with the EU Corporate
Sustainability Reporting Directive will remain eligible once it enters
into force. In addition, we are now looking at setting limits on the
share of assets issued by entities with a high carbon footprint that
banks can pledge as collateral for our lending operations.
Some avenues that we explored did not result in us having to
make any changes. When we reviewed the resilience of the haircuts that
we apply to collateral valuation, we did not find any evidence that
the existing scheme provides insufficient protection against climate-
related financial risks over the horizon for which these haircuts
should provide protection. [12] We will continue to evaluate this in
the future as and when better data become available.
Our
current actions aim to support a high degree of confidence in the
alignment of our activities with the goals set by the Paris Agreement
within our mandate. However, the decarbonisation path for our monetary
policy assets remains dependent on actions that are not fully under
our control, including the decarbonisation efforts made by the issuers
of bonds that we hold. Evaluating, adapting and broadening our actions
to include nature
This is one of the main reasons why we have
made a commitment to regularly review all our measures to assess their
impact. If necessary, we will adapt them to ensure they continue to
fulfil their monetary policy objectives and support the
decarbonisation path to reach the goals set by the Paris Agreement and
the EU climate neutrality objectives. Moreover, we will also look into
addressing additional environmental challenges within our mandate.
Even if the legislative environment on nature preservation is trailing
behind that on climate change – in spite of the landmark Nature
Restoration Law – our initial analyses show that nature-related risks
are highly relevant for the European economy and financial system. Out
of 4. 2 million firms that we looked at, around three million are
highly dependent on at least one ecosystem service, services provided
by nature that are significantly subject to degradation. [13]
Besides making continued efforts to further enhance our
analytical capabilities and deliver on our data needs, what else
should we include when we assess our actions? Given the prevailing
inflation outlook and the need for us to continue to implement a
sufficiently restrictive monetary policy to bring inflation
sustainably back to our 2% target, we do not expect to expand our
balance sheet again anytime soon. However, that doesn’t mean that we
don’t need to continue re-evaluating the fitness of the instruments we
have in our toolkit in case policy adjustments are required. Moreover,
in proceeding with the rundown of our balance sheet, we need to think
about which features we would like to maintain in a steady state.
Our monetary policy strategy enables us to think about both
questions. Specifically, whenever we are faced with two configurations
of the set of instruments that would be equally conducive to
maintaining price stability, we will and legally must choose the one
that best supports the general economic policies in the EU. This
implies that whenever we make a marginal adjustment to the calibration
of our instruments, we must choose the option that increases our
confidence in the plausibility of our decarbonisation path, unless our
proportionality assessment shows that there are other, less intrusive
ways of achieving price stability.
Looking ahead, besides the
adjustments that we are already implementing, I think this principle
may require us to consider two further avenues.
The first
concerns our public sector bond holdings. Here we can apply reasoning
very similar to that applied to our corporate bond holdings.
Currently, the bulk of our monetary policy assets consists of bonds
issued by governments of EU Member States. However, the climate and
nature-related risk intensity of these bonds is not obvious owing to
the absence of a clear and reliable framework to assess their
compatibility with the Paris Agreement. At the same time, since the
pandemic, the universe of supranational bonds issued by EU
institutions has increased significantly, with green bonds
representing a relatively large proportion. [14] In my view, when
there is no clear monetary policy rationale for preferring domestic
sovereign bonds, we should contemplate increasing the share of EU
supranational bonds in our total bond holdings to avoid potential
climate and nature-related risks and to better align our balance sheet
with the general economic policies in the EU. Not only is this
relevant for when we would need to consider new bond purchases. It is
also relevant when we need to discuss the composition of any
structural bond portfolio that we might maintain in the new steady
state.
Second, whenever there is a monetary policy need in the
future to reconsider targeted longer-term refinancing operations for
banks, there are compelling reasons to seriously consider greening
them. A parallel can be drawn with the way that the ECB has in the
past incorporated financial stability considerations into the design
of its instruments. As of the third series that was launched in 2019,
the targeted longer-term refinancing operations (TLTROs) that we
offered banks comprised a lending target that excluded housing loans
to avoid contributing to the formation of real estate bubbles. [15]
Similar targeting strategies can be considered to support green
lending or exclude non-green lending in the future, provided an
operationally efficient validation process is feasible.
Conclusion
Let me conclude.
Alexander von Humboldt, a
pioneer in ecology among many other things, once said, “The most
dangerous worldview is the worldview of those who have never looked at
the world. ”
If we transpose this to the central bank’s
worldview – and to that of the banking supervision arm – the risk of
not delivering on our mandate is real if we don’t take climate and
nature into consideration. Preserving price stability means preserving
climate and nature stability. It is our mandate. It is our culture.
Unsere Stabilitätskultur.
Vielen dank für Ihre Aufmerksamkeit.