Christine Lagarde, Luis de Guindos: Monetary policy statement (with Q&A)
Christine Lagarde, President of the ECB, Luis de Guindos, Vice-
President of the ECBFrankfurt am Main, 12 December 2024 Jump to the
transcript of the questions and answers
Good afternoon, the
Vice-President and I welcome you to our press conference.
The
Governing Council today decided to lower the three key ECB interest
rates by 25 basis points. In particular, the decision to lower the
deposit facility rate – the rate through which we steer the monetary
policy stance – is based on our updated assessment of the inflation
outlook, the dynamics of underlying inflation and the strength of
monetary policy transmission.
The disinflation process is well
on track. Staff see headline inflation averaging 2. 4 per cent in
2024, 2. 1 per cent in 2025, 1. 9 per cent in 2026 and 2. 1 per cent
in 2027 when the expanded EU Emissions Trading System becomes
operational. For inflation excluding energy and food, staff project an
average of 2. 9 per cent in 2024, 2. 3 per cent in 2025 and 1. 9 per
cent in both 2026 and 2027.
Most measures of underlying
inflation suggest that inflation will settle at around our two per
cent medium-term target on a sustained basis. Domestic inflation has
edged down but remains high, mostly because wages and prices in
certain sectors are still adjusting to the past inflation surge with a
substantial delay.
Financing conditions are easing, as our
recent interest rate cuts gradually make new borrowing less expensive
for firms and households. But they continue to be tight because our
monetary policy remains restrictive and past interest rate hikes are
still transmitting to the outstanding stock of credit.
Staff
now expect a slower economic recovery than in the September
projections. Although growth picked up in the third quarter of this
year, survey indicators suggest it has slowed in the current quarter.
Staff see the economy growing by 0. 7 per cent in 2024, 1. 1 per cent
in 2025, 1. 4 per cent in 2026 and 1. 3 per cent in 2027. The
projected recovery rests mainly on rising real incomes – which should
allow households to consume more – and firms increasing investment.
Over time, the gradually fading effects of restrictive monetary policy
should support a pick-up in domestic demand.
We are determined
to ensure that inflation stabilises sustainably at our two per cent
medium-term target. We will follow a data-dependent and meeting-by-
meeting approach to determining the appropriate monetary policy
stance. In particular, our interest rate decisions will be based on
our assessment of the inflation outlook in light of the incoming
economic and financial data, the dynamics of underlying inflation and
the strength of monetary policy transmission. We are not pre-
committing to a particular rate path.
The decisions taken
today are set out in a press release available on our website.
I will now outline in more detail how we see the economy and
inflation developing and will then explain our assessment of financial
and monetary conditions. Economic activity
The economy grew by
0. 4 per cent in the third quarter, exceeding expectations. Growth was
driven mainly by an increase in consumption, partly reflecting one-off
factors that boosted tourism over the summer, and by firms building up
inventories. But the latest information suggests it is losing
momentum. Surveys indicate that manufacturing is still contracting and
growth in services is slowing. Firms are holding back their investment
spending in the face of weak demand and a highly uncertain outlook.
Exports are also weak, with some European industries finding it
challenging to remain competitive.
The labour market remains
resilient. Employment grew by 0. 2 per cent in the third quarter,
again by more than expected. The unemployment rate remained at its
historical low of 6. 3 per cent in October. Meanwhile, demand for
labour continues to weaken. The job vacancy rate declined to 2. 5% in
the third quarter, 0. 8 percentage points below its peak, and surveys
also point to fewer jobs being created in the current quarter.
The economy should strengthen over time, although more slowly
than previously expected. The rise in real wages should strengthen
household spending. More affordable credit should boost consumption
and investment. Provided trade tensions do not escalate, exports
should support the recovery as global demand rises.
Fiscal and
structural policies should make the economy more productive,
competitive and resilient. It is crucial to swiftly follow up, with
concrete and ambitious structural policies, on Mario Draghi’s
proposals for enhancing European competitiveness and Enrico Letta’s
proposals for empowering the Single Market. We welcome the European
Commission’s assessment of governments’ medium-term plans for fiscal
and structural policies, as part of the EU’s revised economic
governance framework. Governments should now focus on implementing
their commitments under this framework fully and without delay. This
will help bring down budget deficits and debt ratios on a sustained
basis, while prioritising growth-enhancing reforms and investment.
Inflation
Annual inflation increased to 2. 3 per cent in
November according to Eurostat’s flash estimate, from 2. 0 per cent in
October. The increase was expected and primarily reflected an energy-
related upward base effect. Food price inflation edged down to 2. 8
per cent and services inflation to 3. 9 per cent. Goods inflation went
up to 0. 7 per cent.
Domestic inflation, which closely tracks
services inflation, again eased somewhat in October. But at 4. 2%, it
remains high. This reflects strong wage pressures and the fact that
some services prices are still adjusting with a delay to the past
inflation surge. That said, underlying inflation is overall developing
in line with a sustained return of inflation to target.
The
increase in compensation per employee moderated to 4. 4 per cent in
the third quarter from 4. 7 per cent in the second. Amid stable
productivity, this contributed to slower growth in unit labour costs.
Staff expect labour costs to increase more slowly over the projection
horizon as a result of lower wage growth and higher productivity
growth. Moreover, profits should continue to partially offset the
effects of higher labour costs on prices, especially in the near term.
We expect inflation to fluctuate around its current level in
the near term, as previous sharp falls in energy prices continue to
drop out of the annual rates. It should then settle sustainably at
around the two per cent medium-term target. Easing labour cost
pressures and the continuing impact of our past monetary policy
tightening on consumer prices should help this process. Most measures
of longer-term inflation expectations stand at around 2 per cent, and
market-based indicators of medium to longer-term inflation
compensation have decreased measurably since the Governing Council’s
October meeting. Risk assessment
The risks to economic growth
remain tilted to the downside. The risk of greater friction in global
trade could weigh on euro area growth by dampening exports and
weakening the global economy. Lower confidence could prevent
consumption and investment from recovering as fast as expected. This
could be amplified by geopolitical risks, such as Russia’s unjustified
war against Ukraine and the tragic conflict in the Middle East, which
could disrupt energy supplies and global trade. Growth could also be
lower if the lagged effects of monetary policy tightening last longer
than expected. It could be higher if easier financing conditions and
falling inflation allow domestic consumption and investment to rebound
faster.
Inflation could turn out higher if wages or profits
increase by more than expected. Upside risks to inflation also stem
from the heightened geopolitical tensions, which could push energy
prices and freight costs higher in the near term and disrupt global
trade. Moreover, extreme weather events, and the unfolding climate
crisis more broadly, could drive up food prices by more than expected.
By contrast, inflation may surprise on the downside if low confidence
and concerns about geopolitical events prevent consumption and
investment from recovering as fast as expected, if monetary policy
dampens demand more than expected, or if the economic environment in
the rest of the world worsens unexpectedly. Greater friction in global
trade would make the euro area inflation outlook more uncertain.
Financial and monetary conditions
Market interest rates in the
euro area have declined further since our October meeting, reflecting
the perceived worsening of the economic outlook. Although financing
conditions remain restrictive, our interest rate cuts are gradually
making it less expensive for firms and households to borrow.
The average interest rate on new loans to firms was 4. 7 per
cent in October, more than half a percentage point below its peak a
year earlier. The cost of issuing market-based debt has fallen by more
than a percentage point since its peak. The average rate on new
mortgages, at 3. 6 per cent in October, is about half a percentage
point lower than at its highest point in 2023, even though the average
rate on the outstanding stock of mortgages is still set to rise.
Bank lending to firms has gradually picked up from low levels,
and increased by 1. 2 per cent in October compared with a year
earlier. Debt securities issued by firms were up 3. 1% in annual
terms, which was similar to the increase in the previous few months.
Mortgage lending continued to rise gradually in October, with an
annual growth rate of 0. 8 per cent.
In line with our monetary
policy strategy, the Governing Council thoroughly assessed the links
between monetary policy and financial stability. Euro area banks
remain resilient and there are few signs of financial market stress.
Financial stability risks nonetheless remain elevated. Macroprudential
policy remains the first line of defence against the build-up of
financial vulnerabilities, enhancing resilience and preserving
macroprudential space. Conclusion
The Governing Council today
decided to lower the three key ECB interest rates by 25 basis points.
In particular, the decision to lower the deposit facility rate – the
rate through which we steer the monetary policy stance – is based on
our updated assessment of the inflation outlook, the dynamics of
underlying inflation and the strength of monetary policy transmission.
We are determined to ensure that inflation stabilises sustainably at
our two per cent medium-term target. We will follow a data-dependent
and meeting-by-meeting approach to determining the appropriate
monetary policy stance. In particular, our interest rate decisions
will be based on our assessment of the inflation outlook in light of
the incoming economic and financial data, the dynamics of underlying
inflation and the strength of monetary policy transmission. We are not
pre-committing to a particular rate path.
In any case, we
stand ready to adjust all of our instruments within our mandate to
ensure that inflation stabilises sustainably at our medium-term target
and to preserve the smooth functioning of monetary policy
transmission.
We are now ready to take your questions.
* * *
I have two questions. The first is on a general
flavour of the arguments which have been exchanged in order to reach
the decision today. What were the key arguments in favour of that 25
basis points rate cut? Second question, you dropped the reference to
keep interest rates restrictive or sufficiently restrictive for the
foreseeable future. Does that also mean that you consider perhaps a
larger rate cut at your next policy meeting, or is that something you
have been discussing, at least?
We had a Governing Council
meeting that was the last of 2024 and which really led us to
acknowledge, not yet the victory against inflation, not yet “mission
accomplished”, but certainly it led us to acknowledge that inflation
was really on track, in terms of reaching our 2% target in the medium-
term. And that gave us a level of confidence to actually decide to cut
and to decide the appropriate cut, which is, in our view, 25 basis
points. That proposal was agreed by all members of the Governing
Council. There were some discussions, with some proposals to consider
possibly 50 basis points. But the overall agreement to which everybody
rallied was that 25 basis points was actually the right decision. And
I think it was predicated on three key elements. The first element is
that inflation in our projections has converged towards 2% for six
projection exercises in a row. So, you probably have forgotten, as I
wish I had, the days when everybody was considering that maybe we
would slip into 2026 and we would not reach 2% in 2025. Well, as I
said, six times in a row, our projections are telling us that we will
be at 2% target in the course of 2025 and if anything, it has moved a
little bit forward in the course of 2025, but suffices to say that in
2025 we shall be at 2%. And that is, you know, clearly reflected in
the projections that we have. I think the second element is that the
fading of past shocks has pushed underlying inflation down. If I look,
for instance, at wages, if I look at profits, and you remember the
discussion that we had many times about the buffer that profits could
exercise to absorb additional labour costs. We are actually seeing
that reality unfolding and the projection for compensation, whether we
look at the wage tracker, whether we look at compensation per
employee, whether we look at the vacancy ratio, all of that is
pointing in the direction of wages gradually, in the course of 2025
reaching a percentage increase that is compatible with our 2% target.
And in terms of profits, we are also observing the same movement, of
growth in profits having declined and being in a position to absorb
some of this labour costs. Productivity: we are beginning to see also
some a little bit more promising numbers. So those three components:
wages, profit, productivity, also heading in the right direction. And
I think the third element that we took into consideration, and that
led us to this decision, is that risk to inflation is now two sided,
clearly, and that led us to making the decision that we've made, but
also removing the reference to restrictiveness that you have
mentioned. And by that, I'm also addressing your second question by
the same token. But having said all that, we still have service
inflation, which is running high. And if we look in particular at
domestic inflation, we are still at 4. 2% and service inflation has
hedged down a little bit from 4 to 3. 9, but it is still resistant,
and we would really want to see a change in the composition of
inflation to feel totally confident that we are really almost at
target.
Coming back to inflation, how do you see risks around
inflation target? Do you feel the risk of undershooting is higher than
the risk of overshooting? And could you give us a sense of those what
those risks are?
You know, the risks to inflation are clearly
stated in our monetary policy statement. And as I have said, they are
more two sided than they were before, and that's really the analysis
that we have about risk to inflation. That's how we look at it.
I'm wondering, when you when you changed that language on the
need for restrictive policies, you must have had a debate about the
neutral rate in one way or another. And I'm just wondering if you can
fill us in a little bit on that debate and maybe share how far you
think, and the Governing Council believes, current policy settings are
from those neutral levels. And the second question I have is that,
after what the market has heard so far, it is now pricing a larger 50
basis point cut for January, and I'm just wondering if you have any
thoughts on that?
No, I don't really think about that, but I
would simply observe that that was the case also a few weeks ago, and
things change over the course of time, depending on data, depending on
assessment of the situation, and this is exactly what we are going to
do. We will continue to be data dependent. We will continue to decide
meeting by meeting. We will continue to not have a pre-committed path
downward, but it will be again based on the three criteria that we
have flagged and that I have repeated at least three times in this
monetary policy statement. I will not inflict a third repetition of
that. That's what we will do, and we are not anticipating X or Y for
the next monetary policy decision that that we will take. A lot is
going to be clarified, we hope, in the next few months, not in the
next few weeks. If there is one thing that we discussed in the last
two days, it's the level of uncertainty that we are facing, and
whether it's uncertainty resulting from political situations in some
of the member states, whether it's uncertainty resulting from the
outcome in terms of policies of the US elections, all of that is
largely a question mark, because there is a distance between the words
and the action taken. So, neutral rate. What I would really recommend
is that you go back to this publication that we had approximately one
year ago, which really discusses the tools and the methods that we all
try to apply in order to determine something that cannot be determined
with great precision, particularly in advance. And those methods are
based on either the inflation, financing, savings, economies, and this
is what is done by our staff, very ably. But have we discussed the
neutral rate in the last couple of days? No.
What happens if
the US set a tariff against Europe? Will the ECB react? And second
question: inflation and core inflation in the medium term will settle
at around 2%, so this is your mandate. Do you think it's time now to
focus on improving the domestic demand and growth, that are both slow
whereas the American economy is vigorous?
The first one about
trade - I've given my views very extensively in a recent Financial
Times interview, and I continue to think that restrictions on trade,
protectionist measures, are not conducive to growth and ultimately
have an impact on inflation that is largely uncertain. In the short
term, it's probably net inflationary, probably, but the overall impact
on inflation is uncertain, because it is going to depend on the scope
of the measures, on the retaliation that is decided, on the rerouting
of trade traffic from other parts of the world, and that is a very
complex situation with movable parts, which we will determine if and
when they come. On your second question, I'm tempted to suggest that
you put it to somebody else, because our focus is price stability.
That is our mandate, and that's the best we can do to help economic
actors to make their decisions and to create growth and create value.
Everybody has to do their job. We have to provide price stability.
Member states in Europe and in the euro area in particular have to
comply and respect the fiscal governance framework that they have
established for themselves, and that includes a combination of fiscal
consolidation and growth-enhancing measures at the same time. And if
other measures which are expected by the economic operators are
delivered, then I don't see any reason why demand would not be
stimulated as a result. But everybody has to do their job. The central
bank cannot be the jack of all trades. We have to do our job, which is
to procure price stability.
I have also a question on this
dropped reference to keeping policy rates sufficiently restrictive.
This was seen as a kind of sign of the tightening bias by many people,
I think also within the ECB, that dropping this reference, does it
mean you now have an easing bias? Or would that be pushing it too far?
Would be interesting to get your thoughts on that. And my second
question would be on the staff projections: I think in September, the
minutes showed that when the projections were presented, there was
already a concern that they might be too optimistic, because of all
kind of things that had happened between the cutoff and the meeting.
Has this been the case again, this time? And did you discuss how to
respond to, in a scenario where those projections turned out to be too
optimistic?
On your first question about restrictiveness, we
are currently restrictive, and it's stated very clearly in the
monetary policy statement, in the fourth paragraph, if I recall, where
we say very clearly that - I want to give you the exact reference so
that we don't make any mistake. It is in the fourth paragraph; we talk
about the financing conditions and we say “but they continue to be
tight because our monetary policy remains restrictive”. So, we are
currently restrictive. There is no questioning in that respect. And
the direction of travel currently is very clear. The pace at which it
happens, the data that will determine it, the method that we will
apply, the meeting by meeting, all of that is quite clear. But, you
know, obviously, a lot of ground has been covered. We have already cut
interest rates four times, a total of 100 basis points. We are now, as
a result of this decision, today, at 3% for the DFR [Deposit facility
rate], and we are in a completely different environment. We are
getting much closer to target. As I said earlier, our projections for
six times in a row indicate convergence towards 2% in 2025. We see
two-sided risk to inflation. So, the macroeconomic landscape in which
we make our decisions is vastly different from the days when we were
at very high inflation, we had a lot of ground to cover, and risk to
inflation was one sided. So as a result of that, it was completely
legitimate and natural to remove that reference to being restrictive
for long enough, to arrive at target in a timely manner. That is the
other word which, as you may have noticed, has disappeared from our
monetary policy statement, timely. Now you asked me a second question.
You said, what about if staff projections are on the optimist side.
First of all, I think that they do those projections in with a great
sense of integrity and loyalty to the facts, to what is
unquestionable, and they apply the best judgment that they can in the
work that they do. So, I have no reason to doubt their projections.
The element which has changed and which has been reinforced, as you
will have noted also in the monetary policy statement, is the downside
risk, particularly downside risk to growth, which is more elaborate in
the wording of the monetary policy statement, and I think that that's
a way to indicate that, given the uncertainty that we have in
abundance, it is also the right approach to beef up the risk
measurement.
My questions are on PEPP [Pandemic emergency
purchasing programme] and on TPI [Transmission protection instrument].
Now, on PEPP, you will not have any more the flexibility of
reinvesting the redemptions coming due at the PEPP portfolio, and you
used it to counter risk to the monetary policy transmission mechanism.
So, what do you think will be this impact of ending this reinvestment
of PEPP, and you will only have now TPI, in a way, to intervene on the
monetary policy mechanism. And at the moment, the spreads are not
moving much, but I must say that the markets are surprised. For
example, on the OAT-Bund spread given such a huge turbulence is not
moving, and some traders are wondering whether you have been using
TPI. But are we ever going to know if you use TPI? At least we knew
you were using the PEPP reinvestments.
You are correct that
PEPP is coming to the end of its active life, because we will stop any
reinvestment as of the 17th of December. This will be the last
reinvestment phase, and it has proven an incredibly efficient tool in
order to fight the pandemic. It was also an extraordinary tool in that
it was associated with flexibility, with no reference to the capital
keys, if you remember, which was also quite a breakthrough and quite
an exceptional tool for exceptional circumstances. I think the last
time we used the flexibility was in July 2023[1]. It hasn't been used
since that, at all. And yes, there was publication on a regular basis.
And I think we will continue to have publications, I think on a
monthly basis, actually, as opposed to the bi-monthly, which was every
other month in the past, just to indicate what is the maturity of
those bonds that are coming to maturity. We did not discuss TPI. And
if you're interested in the conditions and the terms and the
publication and the modalities, there's a great press release which is
out there and which includes all of that.
You said that this
greater confidence on the projections that we are seeing with these
six [projections] in a row, targeting 2% in 2025, I was wondering if
this greater confidence in the projections could lead to assume that
even if we remain data dependent, it's correct to assume that the ECB
is going to cut for the next meeting, unless this data dependency
advised not to, because these projections have a market curve of
interest rate that assume that. My other question is, given this
already pretty low growth in forecast, if they incorporate this
slowing growth rate that we have to expect from the US new
administration or not, and if you like, have a say on that.
It's a general question you have on projections, really. So,
the uncertainty that I referred to, stemming from the policies that
could be decided by the next US administration, is not incorporated in
the baseline. Except, I think from memory, the extension of the tax
reductions that were, in a way, committed by both candidates to the
presidency. I think that portion is included. It has a fiscal
dimension to it, but the trade dimension is only incorporated
indirectly, as you said, through using the yield curve and other
market determined elements, which are only part of the many
assumptions or data that are taken into consideration by staff when
they do their projections. So, the trade uncertainty is captured in
the Risk Assessment section, and we have taken the precaution to add a
full sentence at the end of the risk paragraph to relate to the
friction in relation to trade. And as I said to your colleague earlier
on, it's a risk and of itself it's not good for growth at large. It
produces uncertain inflation impact in the euro area, at least - I
would not pass judgment on what it impacted would have on the on the
US - but it's very tentative and it's very uncertain, and you really
have to dig into it to appreciate what the impact will be. I think you
should appreciate that we are on a path, currently, that leads us to
reach our 2% target medium-term, and that our monetary policy stance,
each and every step of the way, at each meeting will be determined by
the data that we that we have, by the projection that is proposed by
our staff, and will be based on those three criteria that you know
well. So, to assume anything in particular at any point in time, I
think, is not the right approach, because we are going to continue to
be data dependent. We are not pre-committing to a particular path. We
simply indicate by removing the reference to restrictiveness that we
have come a long way. The situation is very different. We are much
closer to a target which we are seeing much more closely now and as a
result of that, we want to remain appropriate in our determination of
monetary policy. If you want to compare apples and apples, it’s
“restrictiveness” goes, “appropriate determination” replaces it,
because we are getting closer, but we're not done. Let's face it, when
you still have 4. 2% domestic inflation and wages of which the growth
is slowing down, you have to be very cautious.
Could you
please elaborate on whether, as you put it, political instability in
certain member states put the reaching of the goal at risk, and how
the ECB can react to it?
I don't comment on any particular
member states. I was simply referring, and I'll refer again in
response to your question, to the uncertainty that is stemming from
the lack of budget submission by several member states. If you ask me
the list, I will be happy to procure it, but there are at least four
of them that are either operating on the basis of an old budget from
2024 or 2023 or that simply do not have it yet. So, uncertainty about
budget, which makes the fiscal projection a little bit complicated.
Uncertainty about the actual political evolution, depending on
elections, appointments or whatever, in several member states. That is
self-inflicted uncertainty that we have nothing to do with, but which
is caused by the current political situations. Things will, again,
probably come to resolution, and we will see better the economic
consequences of those decisions. Clearly, there are elections coming
up in the first quarter of 2025 and hopefully decisions being made
much earlier than that for other member states.
I know that
you don't target exchange rates but inflation wise, would it be an
extra concern if the euro goes below parity? And the second question,
going back to the restrictiveness or not of the monetary policy, it
seems that it remains restrictive, but I was wondering if you could
point out if it is still very restrictive, or just slightly
restrictive, because different members have stated different views in
these terms.
You know, on your latter question, I’m off to
Vilnius on Sunday night, and I will give a speech on those issues in
particular, on Monday. So, I strongly encourage you to look at that
speech. I know you do, so I feel very comfortable referring you to
that. But it really dissects and in great detail this issue of how
restrictive and the sort of the direction forward. On the exchange
rate, you gave half the answer by saying that we do not target
exchange rate, and I repeat that gladly, and obviously, exchange rate
and variations have an impact on inflation, and we are attentive to
that, and we will continue to be attentive to that in the next few
weeks and months.
My question is not related to the monetary
policy direction, but in Germany, a new snap election is planned to be
held next February, and the right party, Alternative for Germany, so
called AFD, plans to call to leave the EU and the euro currency. The
argument is not new, but it seems the support for this party will be
strong in this election, and as the ECB is present, who protects the
euro system democracy? What can you say now?
Well, the
European Union was founded by the founding member states, one of which
was Germany, and it came on the step of a horrible period of time when
member states, currently sitting at the same table were at each
other's throat, and that caused the killing and the dying of many,
many, many Europeans, and I would very much hope that this history,
which is at the root of the construction, stays very clear on the mind
of everyone.
I have one question, also concerning the neutral
rate. There were very different views expressed by different members
that there's a lot of room still, or no room at all? What's your view
on that?
You know, I think this issue of the neutral rate is
one that we will probably debate more and further, as we get closer to
where it eventually is, and we will probably apply the various tools
and methodologies that are suggested by staff in that work that was
published about a year ago. I think the conventional wisdom around the
table is that it is probably a little higher than where it was before,
for multiple reasons, and that we will debate in due course. But it's
premature to do that at the moment, and the numbers, if I recall, that
were flagged by staff in that report, varied from 1. 75 to 2. 5 and
you know, this is the range that is a result of the calculation and
the methodologies that they have suggested. When we get there, I'm
sure that we will be debating that.